• durcxi by thc~sc' l~~rks('fablr I, column 4). Thus, un an an-
<br />nual basis thescr four E~ark~;-219 acres of urban open
<br />5pacc~--generate some $349,195 of external ~~conumic
<br />benefits.
<br />r~
<br />L I
<br />•
<br />ti noted lxfore, however, the external economic
<br />Abenefits represent only a portion of the total eco-
<br />numic value of a park, Tu get a full picture we must aLSo
<br />consider the value of the on-site recreation produced by
<br />the parks. Of course, no one really knows the econo-
<br />mic value of an individual visit to a park. Therefore,
<br />because we wanted tube very conservative, we began by
<br />assuming that each individual visit was worth an
<br />average of $1; that is, in return for the privilege of using
<br />one of these parks, people would be willing to pay an
<br />average of $1 per visit. Of course, this is an assumption in
<br />the truest sense; there are no data to validate it. On the
<br />other hand, $1 seems conservative when one considers
<br />the current market price of many private sector recrea-
<br />tion activities.
<br />Annual attendance figures for three of the parks were
<br />readily available from the Worcester Parks and Recrea-
<br />tion Department (Table 1, column 5). These figures were
<br />not usable directly, however, because many of the park
<br />users lived within 2,000 feet of one of the parks.
<br />Presumably these people have already paid a premium
<br />in their housing costs; to charge them again would be a
<br />sort of double counting which would overestimate the
<br />value of the park. To counter this, we conducted a series
<br />of interviews in each park to determine what percentage
<br />of users lived beyond the 2,000 foot range (Table 1, col-
<br />umn 6). Then, to the adjusted attendance figures (Table 1,
<br />culwlul 7), we applied the $1 value to dc.~termine the an-
<br />nual recreation benefit (Table 1, column 8). Then the total
<br />economic benefits produced annually by the parks (sum
<br />of columns 4 and 8) can be compared to the annual
<br />operating cast Crable 1, column 9)to obtain the overall
<br />relationship of benefits to casts (Table 1, column 10).
<br />Overall, these 219 acres of urban parkland generate
<br />annually $424,597 of economic value for the city of Wor-
<br />ct~ster. Obviously this is substantially in excess of the
<br />$125,000 that it costs the city each year to operate them;
<br />the ratio of benefits to costs is +3.40.
<br />As we suspected, however, all the areas did equally
<br />well. In fact, under our current assumption that the value
<br />of a visit is worth $1, the cuts of the Elm-Beaverbrouk
<br />complex exceed the value of the benefits it supplies. This
<br />would change, of course, if one assi~ed a different dollar
<br />value to an individual visit. On the other end of the scale,
<br />the benefits of Greenwood Park exceeded the casts by
<br />nearly $140,000 annually.
<br />Obviously, the net benefits (total benefits minus costs)
<br />produced by individual parks vary substantially.
<br />Realistically, the quantity of benefits produced by any in-
<br />dividual park will reflect both the characteristics of the
<br />park (size, degree of development fur active recreation,
<br />aesthetic caliber, and so forth) and the characteristics of
<br />the surrounding neighborhood (residential density, eco-
<br />nomic level, age composition, and so forth). Unfor-
<br />tunately, the number of parks in our study was too small
<br />to permit us to identify exactly how each characteristic
<br />affected benefits. It does appear, however, that there is a
<br />tendency for the property value benefit to be maximized
<br />by parks which emphasize natural open space as op-
<br />lx>bctif to intenx development for organiu~d recreation.
<br />This is consistant with the finding of a 1973 study by
<br />Welcher and Zxrbst in Ohio. In fact, it may well be that
<br />on-site recreation benefits and external property value
<br />benefits are not compatible; as the level of use rises, the
<br />property value benefit declines (Table 1). Finding ways to
<br />optimize both will be a major challenge for future park
<br />designers and landscape architects. In the meantime,
<br />researchers must keep trying to identify those elements
<br />of parks that will maximize the different benefits and
<br />provide more documentation of fhe dollar value of on-
<br />site recreation experiences.
<br />Despite these uncertainties, this research clearly shows
<br />that the value of benefits generated by urban parks
<br />greatly exceeds their operating cost. Obviously these
<br />parks are a vital part of everyday city life. Our profes-
<br />sional challenge in an era of growing fiscal austerity will
<br />be to provide more hard documentation of their value.
<br />EDITOR'S NOTE: For more information vn the research
<br />studies cited within this article, contact Dr. Thomas
<br />Stevens, Dept. of Food and Resource Economics, University
<br />of Massachusetts, Amherst, MA 01003.
<br />Please circle reader service card number 14
<br />PARKS & RECREATIONJAUGUST 1982 33
<br />For catalog call toll-free 8p0/547-1940
<br />
|